Diagnosing China’s Low-Demand, Low-Price Equilibrium: A Mathematical and Sectoral Breakdown, and Why Beijing’s External Posture is Shifting Toward India under Rising U.S. Pressure
Analytical Conversations: From Trendlines to Thought Line

Diagnosing China’s Low-Demand,
Low-Price Equilibrium: A Mathematical and Sectoral Breakdown, and Why Beijing’s
External Posture is Shifting Toward India under Rising U.S. Pressure
Executive
Summary (TL;DR)
China’s economy in 2024–25 faces a
stubborn combination of weak consumption, contracting investment, and sectoral
imbalances. Consumer price deflation (~−0.4% in August 2025) signals
insufficient demand. Growth forecasts by multilateral agencies (IMF, World
Bank) hover at 4.5–4.8%, underscoring a persistent slowdown compared with
earlier double-digit booms. Property sector deleveraging, precautionary
household savings, credit frictions, and aging demographics feed into this weak
equilibrium.
A mathematical decomposition of GDP
growth shows that small declines in consumption and investment can offset
modest gains from fiscal spending and net exports, leaving aggregate growth
subdued. The Phillips curve framework explains the persistence of deflationary
pressures.
Sectoral breakdowns reveal:
- Property:
the biggest drag on investment and household wealth.
- Manufacturing:
squeezed between global demand uncertainty and domestic restructuring.
- Retail & Services:
dampened by high savings and low consumer confidence.
Beijing has adopted targeted fiscal
and credit interventions rather than massive stimulus, fearing leverage risks
and external capital flight. Geopolitically, China is recalibrating: pursuing
transactional commercial ties with India, recalculating its economic
commitments to Pakistan’s CPEC, and navigating U.S. trade and technology
pressure.
The policy challenge lies in lifting
domestic demand sustainably while balancing geopolitical risks.
1.
Key Macro Facts (Empirical Anchors)
- Consumer prices:
Headline CPI turned negative in mid-2025. In August 2025, CPI was −0.4%
year-on-year (TradingEconomics), consistent with deflationary pressures.
- Growth forecasts:
IMF’s World Economic Outlook (2025) projects ~4.6–4.8% growth; World
Bank’s June 2025 update echoes this trajectory, citing weak consumption
and high uncertainty.
- Industrial/retail performance: Reuters (Sept 2025) reported a 0.9% rise in
industrial profits (Jan–Aug 2025) with a rebound in August, yet retail
sales and factory output remain below historic norms.
These three facts frame the entire
analysis: deflation, muted growth, and uneven sectoral performance.
2.
A Mathematical Diagnosis: GDP Decomposition and Demand Gap
2.1
Expenditure identity
Real GDP:
Y=C+I+G+(X−M)
Approximate growth decomposition:
ΔY≈sCΔC+sIΔI+sGΔG+sXΔX
where s⋅s_{\cdot}s⋅ denote expenditure shares.
2.2
China’s expenditure structure
- sC≈0.40s_C \approx (consumption)
- sI≈0.35s_I \approx (investment)
- sG≈0.15s_G \approx (government)
- sNX≈0.10s_{NX} \ (net exports)
2.3
Numerical illustration
Suppose 2025 changes are:
- ΔC = 0% (flat consumption)
- ΔI = −1% (investment contraction)
- ΔG = +1% (modest fiscal expansion)
- Δ(X−M) = +0.5% (weak imports improve net exports)
Plugging in:
ΔY≈0.40(0)+0.35(−1)+0.15(1)+0.10(0.5)
This small negative aligns with
real-world moderation from ~5% growth to mid-4%.
2.4
Demand gap and Phillips curve
Define output gap:
gt=Yt−Y∗g_t = Y_t - Y^*gt=Yt−Y∗
Inflation dynamics:
πt=πt−1+αgt+ϵt\pi_t = \pi_{t-1} +
\alpha g_t + \epsilon_tπt=πt−1+αgt+ϵt
With gt<0g_t < 0gt<0,
inflation falls. China’s observed deflation (−0.4%) suggests a persistent
negative gap, driven mainly by weak consumption and investment.
China’s economic structure can be
explained through the lens of national income accounting. In simple terms, the
total production of the economy—its gross domestic product—is made up of four
major forces: household consumption, business and real estate investment,
government expenditure, and the difference between exports and imports.
Economists measure the change in GDP by observing how much each of these four
parts expands or contracts, while also considering how large their share is in
the overall economy.
Currently, household consumption in
China accounts for less than half of total economic activity, roughly about
two-fifths. Investment, particularly in infrastructure and real estate, forms
about one-third. Government spending contributes close to one-sixth, while net
exports provide the remaining share of around one-tenth. With such a structure,
even a small decline in household spending or private investment can pull
overall growth down significantly.
To illustrate this, imagine a
scenario where household consumption remains flat, showing no increase from the
previous year. At the same time, private investment falls slightly, say by
around one percent. Meanwhile, the government increases its expenditure by
about one percent, and net exports improve modestly by half a percent, largely
because imports have weakened. When all these effects are combined, the decline
in investment outweighs the positive contributions from government and exports,
leaving the economy with negligible growth. This matches recent forecasts by
international institutions that expect China’s growth to slip from around five
percent to closer to four and a half percent.
Another important perspective is the
idea of an “output gap.” This measures the distance between how much an economy
is currently producing and how much it could produce if all its resources—workers,
machines, and land—were fully employed. When actual production falls short of
potential, the economy experiences slack. In such situations, businesses are
unable to raise prices easily because demand is weak, while households cut back
on spending. Economists call this the Phillips-curve effect: low demand puts
downward pressure on prices, and if this continues, the economy may experience
deflation. China is showing signs of exactly this trend—consumer prices in
August 2025 were about half a percent lower than a year earlier, reflecting how
demand weakness has spilled into falling prices.
3.
Sectoral Anatomy
Property
& Investment
- Once contributing ~25–30% of GDP (direct + indirect),
property now drags growth.
- Developer defaults and presale collapses reduce both
III and household wealth effects, dampening CCC.
- Local governments reliant on land sales face shrinking
revenue, curbing fiscal capacity.
Manufacturing
& Exports
- Industrial profits rebounded 0.9% (Reuters, 2025), but
masks stress in consumer durables and export sectors.
- Trade restrictions on semiconductors and advanced
manufacturing weigh on expectations.
- Export gains are uneven: EVs and green tech strong,
traditional consumer goods weak.
Services
& Retail
- Retail sales growth remains below 2% (2025, NBS data).
- Services sectors (hospitality, leisure) fail to recover
strongly, suggesting households prefer saving.
4.
Transmission Channels
4.1
Household precautionary savings
C=(1−s)YC = (1 - s)YC=(1−s)Y
If saving rate sss rises from 35% to
37%, consumption share falls ~2 percentage points of GDP. This alone can drag
growth by ~0.8 percentage points.
4.2
Banking system
- Risk aversion toward property developers and LGFVs
curtails lending.
- Credit growth flows mainly to “strategic” industries,
not households or SMEs.
4.3
Demographics
- Working-age population peaked in 2015; dependency
ratios rising.
- Potential output Y∗Y^*Y∗ slowing, meaning even small demand shocks can push CPI
negative.
5.
Policy Toolkit
Tools
deployed
- Targeted fiscal spending (urban renovation, green
projects).
- Tax relief for SMEs.
- Vouchers in select provinces to stimulate service
demand.
- Regulatory easing for some property projects.
Constraints
- Broad stimulus risks re-leveraging property.
- External trade friction reduces fiscal multiplier.
- Currency stability constrains monetary easing.
Result: surgical, micro-targeted
interventions.
6.
Geopolitical–Economic Angle
6.1
China and India
- Bilateral trade ~US$120bn (2024), with China exporting
electronics, machinery; India exporting iron ore, cotton.
- China sees India as:
- Large consumer market.
- Supply-chain diversification node (hedging against
U.S. tariffs).
- Engagement remains transactional — business-driven, not
strategic alignment.
6.2
China and Pakistan
- CPEC: >US$60bn pledged; yet security risks,
political instability, and debt service concerns slow implementation.
- Shift from mega-infrastructure toward green/renewable
projects with clearer revenue models.
- Interpretation: not abandonment, but recalibration for
financial sustainability.
6.3
U.S. pressure
- Tariffs and export controls on semiconductors, AI,
telecom equipment.
- Raises uncertainty premium for Chinese firms, dampens
investment III.
- Pushes Beijing to double down on self-reliance while
diversifying trade ties (India, ASEAN, Africa).
7.
Scenarios and Benchmarks
Scenario
A: Gentle Recovery (Base Case)
- ΔC = +2%, ΔI = +1%, ΔG = +1%.
- Growth: 4.8–5.0%. Inflation returns to ~+0.5%.
Scenario
B: Stagnation
- ΔC = 0%, ΔI = −2%, exports flat.
- Growth <4%. CPI negative for 6+ quarters.
Scenario
C: Big Stimulus
- Fiscal expansion 3–4% of GDP.
- Growth near 6%, but debt/GDP rises and RMB depreciation
risk.
Benchmarks for policymakers:
- Household consumption growth >3% yoy.
- CPI must revert >0% within 4 quarters.
- Property completion rate >90% for presold units (to
restore confidence).
8.
Policy Recommendations
- Targeted consumption vouchers: If each 0.5% of GDP program raises ΔC by 1%, GDP
growth lifts ~0.4pp.
- Property confidence via completion guarantees: escrow + delivery assurance restores household wealth
effect.
- SME loan guarantees:
partial risk-sharing can lift investment without broad credit loosening.
- Multilateral engagement: reduce tariff risks via regional trade pacts.
- Geoeconomic diplomacy:
- Treat India as complementary partner in trade + supply
chains.
- Reframe Pakistan projects toward bankable, green
ventures.
- Balance U.S. pressure by accelerating tech
self-reliance.
Conclusion
China’s economy in 2025 is not
collapsing but stuck in a low-demand, low-price equilibrium. GDP
arithmetic shows even modest declines in consumption and investment outweigh
gains elsewhere. The Phillips curve framework explains why deflation persists.
Externally, Beijing’s recalibration
reflects pragmatism: leaning toward Indian commerce, tightening project
viability in Pakistan, and responding to U.S. restrictions with
diversification. The path forward requires confidence restoration at home
(property, consumption) and strategic engagement abroad (India for
markets, Pakistan for stability, U.S. for containment).
The challenge is to engineer
sustainable demand growth without repeating the debt-driven cycles of the past.
Micro-targeted fiscal support, credible property measures, and SME investment
support remain the best levers.
References
- TradingEconomics. China Inflation Rate (CPI),
August 2025.
- IMF. World Economic Outlook, Country Data: China,
2025 projections.
- World Bank. China Economic Update, June 2025.
- Reuters. China’s industrial profits rise 0.9% in
Jan–Aug 2025, September 2025.
- China Briefing. China–India Trade Data and Trends,
2024–25.
- Carnegie Endowment. India–China Economic Ties:
Determinants and Possibilities, August 2025.
- Wikipedia. China–Pakistan Economic Corridor (CPEC).
- Council on Foreign Relations. U.S. Export Controls
and Trade Restrictions on China, 2024–25.
Case-Cum-Story:
The Numbers Behind China’s Slowdown
In 2025, Professor Li, an economics
lecturer in Beijing, decided to explain China’s slowdown to his students
through a real-life example. He began by drawing the basic GDP formula on the
board:
Y=C+I+G+(X−M)
“Think of this like a family
budget,” he said. “Household consumption is what families spend daily,
investment is what businesses and real estate developers put into new projects,
government spending is like community welfare, and net exports are what we sell
to the world minus what we buy from it.”
The class nodded. To make it
clearer, Li created a simplified snapshot of China’s economy:
- Household consumption (CCC) = 40% of GDP
- Investment (III) = 30%
- Government spending (GGG) = 20%
- Net exports (X−MX - MX−M) = 10%
He then asked: “What happens if
households stop increasing their spending because they are worried about job
security? Suppose consumption growth is zero. At the same time, investment in
real estate shrinks by 1%. The government tries to help, increasing its
spending by 1%. Meanwhile, net exports rise slightly, by half a percent,
because imports are weak.”
Using the weighted growth
contribution formula, he showed the calculation:
ΔY=(0.40×0%)+(0.30×−1%)+(0.20×1%)+(0.10×0.5%)
-
“See,” Professor Li explained, “even
with the government spending more and exports giving a small boost, the fall in
investment drags the entire economy close to zero growth.”
Then he connected it to the output
gap:
Output Gap=Y−Y∗Y∗\text{Output Gap} = \frac{Y - Y^*}{Y^*}
China’s actual GDP growth was 4.5%,
while potential GDP was estimated at 6%. That meant the economy was running
below capacity:
4.5−66=−0.25 or −25%\frac{4.5 -
6}{6} = -0.25
“This negative gap,” Li said,
“creates slack. Factories stand idle, and workers cannot find jobs.”
Finally, he drew the Phillips
Curve:
πt=πt−1−α(ut−u∗)+εt\pi_t = \pi_{t-1} - \alpha (u_t - u^*) + \varepsilon_tπt=πt−1−α(ut−u∗)+εt
He explained that unemployment had
risen slightly above the natural rate. “That’s why consumer prices in August
2025 were 0.5% lower than last year. Weak demand pushes inflation downward,
sometimes even into deflation.”
The students suddenly realized the
link: behind the abstract formulas were real stories of families cutting
spending, construction projects stalling, and shops lowering prices to attract
hesitant customers.
Professor Li closed the lecture:
“Economics is not just numbers; it’s about people. When investment falls, jobs
vanish. When households lose confidence, spending stops. The formulas simply
show us the chain reaction.”
Comments
Post a Comment